Wednesday, November 26, 2008
Reviving the Monroe Doctrine
Saturday, November 22, 2008
Does this signal deflation?
Monday, November 17, 2008
Everyone's champion
- No preseason polls. First poll will come out after every team has played four games. Preseason rankings are subjective conjecture at best. The absence of a preseason poll will not impact how teams play or prepare. If anything, the first few weeks of the season are a good time for teams to prove themselves and vie for coveted spots.
- In the first year of the system, any conference with 10 or more teams will be split into an Upper and Lower Brackets rather than on geographic lines. The five or six best will occupy the Upper Bracket. To be considered title eligible, each UB team has to play all the other UB teams. To complete a seven game conference schedule, each UB team will play two or three of the Lower Bracket opponents. This part of the schedule will be determined by athletic directors. After the end of Year One, the UB will relegate 2 teams. The LB will promote 2 teams. This will eliminate the need for a conference title game. Though a lesser team upsetting a favorite makes for good drama, it makes consensus - the much sought after purpose - impossible under the present system. Since there will be fewer regular season games, bracket games will have the same import as division games in professional football.
- Given the prospect of relegation, a team which would like to compete for the national championship will have to schedule worthy non-conference opponents. If Oklahoma had an off year in the Big 12, non-conference games against SEC, Big 10, and ACC powers might salvage a season when its in-conference schedule is soft. The current system disproportionately favors teams lucky enough to avoid the toughest competition in its own conference. Wisconsin once skated through the Big 10 without having to play Michigan or Ohio State. Albeit rare, such phenomena would not occur with the bracket format.
- No Cupcake Rule - Scheduling lesser competition for glorified scrimmages encourages bad sportsmanship and needlessly pads the statistics. Glorified scrimmages help no one. Scheduling Florida or Nebraska might look nice on a small school resume. It might get a recruit. However, no student, fan or alumnus can be proud of a 73-0 pasting. Any school scheduling an FCS opponent ought not to be considered for a national title.
- Maintain a computer formula, but eliminate the incentive to run up the score. Including margin of victory in the ranking formula also encourages bad sportsmanship. Margin of victory is borderline irrelevant in the NFL, a league with much more parity amongst its clubs than even the top 32 college teams. Tie breakers will come down to bracket record, overall conference record, and head to head record. In a five or six team bracket, it is unlikely that three team will have the same conference record if they would share more common opponents than they do now. Moreover, multiple loss teams seldom merit national championship consideration.
- An eight team playoff at the end of the season will determine a national champion. Seven of the marquee bowl venues will host the playoffs. The title game can rotate among the oldest established bowls, but few would quibble if the Rose Bowl hosted the last college game of the year. Moreover, a playoff system would not fragment the season between two academic terms. If the first weekend in December were to be the last in the regular season, then two weeks of playoff games following final examinations would make sense. The national championship could take place New Year's Day. Eight teams suffice for logistical purposes, and regression analysis using the BCS formula will show huge drops between the rating of the eighth and ninth teams each year. Also, elimination games produce great drama; the NCAA basketball tournaments provide good evidence of that.
The one argument against incorporating a playoff system is ironically an economic one. Demand for football is high, so why kill the cash cow? Decreasing the total number of games played would be economically unwise because demand is high and relatively inelastic. Therefore, limiting the total number of games played by each school reduces the value of future television contracts. However, demand and clamor for a playoff system to determine a champion are high as well. When observers and coaches find that the current system distorts competition, then change is appropriate.
Since the pressing need is to find consensus, perhaps protecting vested economic interests ought to matter less. College football does provide tangible and intangible benefits for even loss making teams. A model which would compel incumbent powerhouses to behave more competitively is in every one's interest. Though first person participation and the number of televised games would decrease at first, consistently good match ups each week would drive up the value of each game, and hence the price. If revenue for a good albeit flawed product is high, would revenue for an improved version though sold in slightly less quantity be higher? In principle, the answer is yes. Until one can prove that the status quo would continue to generate more interest, higher returns, and protect the integrity of the game, then the NCAA, the networks, and the schools themselves must review all possible ways of abandoning an anodyne, inefficient approach to determining a winner.
Tuesday, November 11, 2008
Stack and tilt economics
- In winter 2000, it was common knowledge that recession was imminent. Rather than brace for recession, Greenspan opted for a soft landing. In hindsight, when much of the lost wealth was in paper assets due to rampant equity speculation, the segment of the population hardest hit would have been the wealthy. Not a chance of a correction taking place with Republican dominance of executive and legislature.
- In winter 2001, when the fallout of the dot-com era exposed malfeasance from faulty business models to disingenuous analytics to plain, old book-cooking (Tyco, Enron, WorldCom), the hastilycobbled Sarbanes-Oxley Act did little to give regulators the resources and scope to deal with crises in the future. "Self-regulation," came the cry. Good job.
Now, when policy decisions have affected not just the leisure or investor classes, but people whose meager net worth is tied solely to the value of their home and the amount of debt they have against the property value, no one is quite sure which is an advantageous step. Concomitantly, high stock market volatility, huge drops in global commodity demand, unfathomable levels of foreign and sovereign debt for the developed world are all symptoms of the collapse in credit markets. Moreover, a coordinated bailout of American investment and retail banks simultaneously doubled the national debt ceiling. The last decade has created a culture within the financial services industry that it is their birthright to have high yield on anything they touch. How is any of this fundamentally sound?
- Offer higher deposit rates - Current interbank rates are higher than ever even as risk premium for safe investments. What better way to access a lending capital pool then by paying out more than a paltry 2%? If banks offered short term CDs one percent below interbank lending rates, many depositors would queue up in no time.
- Scrap the Paulson plan - No Fed Policing. Plain and simple. An expanded Fed cannot act as uber-enforcer of the rules. It contravenes its original mandate which it has seemingly failed to fulfill as of late. A bureaucratic expansion would do no one any good.
- Reconcile the tax base - Short term increases? Distinctly possible, but economic crisis exposes structural defects as well as cyclical. While existing efforts untangle the fiasco at hand, the incoming administration must come up with an alternative to income tax.
- Leverage ratios for investment banks - Light touch regulation such as this may seem like a capital control, but when pension fund portfolios are exposed to highly leveraged firms Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers, the onus of default adversely selects the wrong shareholder. Also, why should Goldman Sachs enjoy a 2000:1 leverage to asset ratio? No one ought to be able to borrow 2000 times above his worth.
- Proportionate funding of existing regulatory agencies - Given the scale by which the federal government has expanded the last eight years, it would be interesting to see the percent change in annual budgets across the myriad agencies. The SEC, FTC, CFTC and DOJ Antitrust division probably did not receive much largess. Adequate funding would allow these regulatory agencies to do their job in real time, learn how to treat complex derivatives, and not be forced to act ad hoc during a crisis. The regulatory and legal framework does a lot to reduce the risk of default. It is a quasi-gold standard, and the country cannot afford to see it diminished.
- Tight money - To keep foreign investors keen during retrenchment as well as to combat inflationary pressure, Treasury will buy back its securities. The Fed will raise interest rates. Consequently, the higher yield on our bonds is more attractive. It will have to be, if politicians balk at enacting the change which got them elected this year, though such structural change will be quite painful.
This nadir in economic history will end, though probably not soon. There are three asset price bubbles from which Western and developed economies not quite recovered. Economists and policy makers should stop reinventing the wheel and simply stick to true fundamentals. Then, everyone can benefit, for the culture of double dealing and lack of accountability ought to be coming to an end. Ditch the Stack and Tilt, and then things can get to the right side.